sabato 16 novembre 2013

Krugman- Bini Smaghi






L’austerità non è solo figlia della stupidità
Lorenzo Bini Smaghi 

In appendice, uno scritto di Paul Robin Krugman







C'é chi come Bini Smaghi pone l'accento sulle riforme strutturali; per il presidente dell'euro parlamento, Martin Schulz, nell'intervista di ieri a Repubblica, l'accento va posto sulla "sostenibilità del consolidamento dei bilanci pubblici, che può funzionare solo con investimenti, crescita e occupazione che rafforzino il consumo"; sempre  Bini Smaghi punta sulla ricapitalizzazione del sistema bancario, altri, invece, alla rinegoziazione delle regole comunitarie da posizioni di forza, altri ancora sull'uscita dall'euro, demonizzato come l'artefice di tutti i mali;  Krugman, oggi su la repubblica, parla di trappola dell'euro, elogia gli sforzi di Draghi per proteggere la moneta europea, dà le sue ricette per farla funzionare. 
 Il dibattito é aperto.

AUSTERITÀ E RECESSIONE
Le misure di austerità sono controproducenti. Provocano effetti recessivi che, almeno nel breve periodo, fanno crescere il debito pubblico. Ma i politici europei continuano a insistere con queste politiche. Per stupidità o per una mancanza di alternative dovuta al rinvio delle riforme strutturali?

La recente crisi dell’Eurozona ha dimostrato che le misure di austerità sono controproducenti: provocano effetti recessivi che, almeno nel breve periodo, tendono a far crescere il debito pubblico, in rapporto al Pil. È una tesi confermata dall’analisi econometrica che mostra come gli aggiustamenti di bilancio siano stati più recessivi del previsto, con moltiplicatori fiscali superiori dell’unità. (1)
Gli effetti particolarmente restrittivi dell’austerità sono ben illustrati nella figura 1, che ripropone un recente grafico di Paul Krugman per il New York Times. (2)
La correlazione negativa tra le misure di austerità messe in atto dai paesi dell’area euro tra il 2008 e il 2012, così come misurate dall’Fmi, e il tasso di crescita nello stesso periodo appare forte, con il coefficiente maggiore di 1. La conclusione che se ne trae è che l’austerità non è il modo migliore per curare le finanze pubbliche.
Nasce allora una domanda: perché i politici dell’Eurozona continuano a fare lo stesso errore? La risposta implicita di Krugman è che i politici non sono particolarmente intelligenti, o sono stati mal consigliati, e hanno sottostimato gli effetti delle loro politiche. Detto in parole diverse, perseguendo l’austerità i politici europei si dimostrano ignoranti in fatto di economia, o stupidi.

Figura 1 - Austerità e crescita
Assumere che i politici siano irrazionali o stupidi è una facile via di uscita, specialmente per gli accademici. Un modo alternativo di guardare alla questione è interrogarsi sulla causalità nella correlazione tra austerità e crescita. Krugman ritiene che con le misure di austerità i politici europei mostrino la loro irrazionalità, o stupidità: sono stupidi perché perseguono l’austerità invece di una opzione politica preferibile.
Per parte mia, vorrei sollevare un dubbio: non potrebbe essere il contrario? I politici europei non sono stupidi perché perseguono l’austerità, ma perseguono l’austerità perché sono stupidi, o detto in modo più diplomatico, hanno una visione ristretta, hanno ignorato le altre alternative a disposizione e alla fine si sono ritrovati con una sola opzione, l’austerità. In altre parole, hanno attuato l’austerità perché non erano rimaste altre scelte.
Vorrei utilizzare la stessa metodologia di Krugman per illustrare il mio punto, con qualche avvertenza sui suoi limiti: un campione composto di sole undici osservazioni dovrebbe essere utilizzato con grande cautela, è molto probabile che i risultati siano distorti, specialmente per la presenza di casi particolari. Il mio intervento, perciò, dovrebbe essere interpretato come un invito a svolgere analisi ulteriori e più sofisticate.
Quello che colpisce nel grafico proposto da Krugman è come la correlazione dipenda molto dalla Grecia. Ma la Grecia è un caso davvero molto particolare, nel quale una dose altissima di austerità è stata imposta a un’economia caratterizzata da forti rigidità e inefficienze. E infatti se dal campione escludiamo la Grecia, come nella figura 2, la correlazione scende in modo drastico.

Figura 2 – Austerità e crescita (Grecia esclusa)

I risultati suggeriscono che la crescita economica dell’Eurozona è stata influenzata anche da altri fattori, diversi dall’austerità. Il prossimo passo è dunque evidenziare, una alla volta, le variabili che possono spiegare i differenziali di crescita tra i paesi dell’Eurozona.

CONDIZIONI DI FINANZIAMENTO

La prima variabile che prendiamo in esame sono le condizioni di finanziamento: i paesi con più alti tassi di interesse dovrebbero aver sperimentato una più bassa crescita, a causa delle più rigide condizioni di finanziamento per l’economia nel suo insieme. La figura 3 mette in correlazione crescita e condizioni di finanziamento, misurata dagli spread sui tassi di interesse per i titoli di Stato a lunga scadenza. La correlazione è relativamente forte e ciò suggerisce che i paesi con un rischio credito più alto hanno sofferto di condizioni più restrittive, che hanno portato a una più bassa crescita.
Naturalmente, il risultato va preso con cautela. La correlazione nasconde il fatto che dal 2008 i paesi con più alto debito hanno dovuto adottare misure di austerità. Tuttavia, il significato della correlazione, se confrontato con quella precedente, suggerisce che anche la rigidità delle condizioni di finanziamento ha avuto un ruolo significativo nello spiegare l’andamento economico. In altre parole, i paesi con un rischio credito più elevato sul loro debito hanno sofferto di più.

Figura 3 – Condizioni di finanziamento e crescita

Si può estendere l’analisi per considerare la correlazione tra rischio sovrano e rischio bancario, che spiega l’inasprimento relativo delle condizioni di credito nei paesi periferici. La figura 4 mostra la correlazione tra crescita e condizioni di credito, indicate dagli spread relativi ai tassi di interesse sui prestiti praticati dalle banche. La correlazione è forte e ciò suggerisce che le condizioni di finanziamento delle aziende sono state un importante fattore nello spiegare le differenze di crescita tra paesi dell’Eurozona. I paesi che hanno avuto crescenti difficoltà a finanziare il loro debito pubblico durante la crisi hanno sofferto sia di una stretta creditizia, evidenziata da un credito bancario più costoso, sia dell’impatto dell’aggiustamento fiscale.

Figura 4 – Condizioni di credito e crescita

LA COMPETITIVITÀ


Un passo avanti ulteriore nella nostra analisi è guardare oltre le politiche economiche e considerare i più profondi problemi strutturali. Un punto di partenza sono gli squilibriaccumulati nei primi anni di unione monetaria, in termini di competitività e di potenziali di crescita.
La figura 5 considera i mutamenti di competitività, misurata dal costo del lavoro per unità, accumulati dall’introduzione dell’euro fino all’anno precedente la crisi; mostra che i paesi che hanno perso competitività prima della crisi hanno sperimentato la crescita più bassa dopo la crisi.

Figura 5 – Competitività e crescita

La correlazione tra competitività e crescita appare particolarmente forte anche quando si considerano altri fattori fondamentali, come quelli utilizzati dal World Economic Forum per classificare l’attrattività dei paesi per gli investitori.

Figura 6 – Competitività (Wef) e crescita

IL POTENZIALE DI CRESCITA

La figura 6 suggerisce che il tasso di crescita dopo la crisi è influenzato pesantemente dai divari di competitività createsi prima della crisi: i paesi che sono agli ultimi posti nelle classifiche di competitività sono anche quelli che hanno registrato la minore crescita dopo la crisi.
Ne abbiamo conferma se guardiamo a più specifici indicatori del potenziale di crescita di lungo periodo.
Tra questi indicatori si possono considerare, per esempio, l’accesso a internet o le competenze in matematica, misurate nello Skills Outlook Report dell’Ocse pubblicato nell’ottobre 2013. Le figure 7 e 8 mostrano una forte correlazione tra la crescita dei paesi dell’area euro negli anni della crisi e queste variabili strutturali. I risultati indicano che l’andamento economico all’interno dell’Eurozona negli anni recenti non si spiega solo con le politiche macroeconomiche, ma con fattori più profondi, che sono in relazione con il potenziale di crescita.

Figura 7 – Accesso a internet e crescita

Figura 8 – Competenze matematiche e crescita


Pur con le consuete cautele, l’esercizio permette di sollevare alcune domande interessanti. Per esempio, se la crescita è correlata negativamente con l’accesso a internet e le competenze in matematica e se la crescita è correlata negativamente anche con l’austerità, c’è una relazione tra le due variabili considerate esogene, cioè l’accesso a internet e l’austerità? La figura 9 mostra che esiste una forte correlazione tra le due: i paesi con minore accesso a internet hanno attuato maggiori misure di austerità. Ma qual è il significato di tutto ciò?
Potrebbe significare che la relazione tra austerità e crescita è più complicata di quanto pensano gli economisti. Nel guardare all'andamento della crescita durante la crisi, i macro economisti sono inclini a considerare le specifiche politiche realizzate, senza chiedersi perché siano state seguite. L’ipotesi che i politici siano mal consigliati o irrazionali piace agli accademici, che tendono a disprezzare i politici. Tuttavia, possono esserci ipotesi alternative.

Figura 9 – Accesso a internet e austerità

Non è l’austerità che ha causato la bassa crescita, è la bassa crescita che ha causato l’austerità. In altri termini, i paesi che hanno sperimentato una bassa crescita potenziale, a causa di profondi problemi strutturali, nel tentativo di sostenere il loro standard di vita e il loro sistema di welfare hanno accumulato, prima della crisi, un eccesso di debito pubblico e privato, che poi, quando la crisi è scoppiata, si è rivelato insostenibile e ha richiesto un brusco aggiustamento.
L’austerità ha certamente prodotto una bassa crescita, ma essa stessa può essere il risultato di una crescita scarsa e squilibrata, a causa della mancanza di riforme strutturali. Il rinvio di riforme che migliorassero il potenziale di crescita ha lasciato i paesi con un’unica soluzione, l’austerità. L’austerità è così il risultato dell’incapacità dei politici di prendere decisioni nel momento giusto, in altre parole è il risultato della loro miopia – e della stupidità.(3)
La via di uscita dall’austerità non passa allora dalla riduzione delle misure di austerità, ma da profonde riforme strutturali che aumentino il potenziale di crescita e creino spazi di manovra per un aggiustamento fiscale più graduale.
(1) Blanchard, O. and D. Leigh ”Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers” IMF Working paper 13/1, Jan 2013
(2) Krugman, P. “How the Case for Austerity has Crumbled”, The New York Review of Books, 6 June 2013.
(3) Bini Smaghi, L. “Austerity: European Democracies against the Wall”, Ceps, July 2013; pubblicato in Italia con il titolo “Morire di Austerita’: Democrazie europee con le spalle al muro- Il Mulino 2013

Fonte: lavoce.info


Il parere di Krugman
Fonte: the New York reviews of books 

In normal times, an arithmetic mistake in an economics paper would be a complete nonevent as far as the wider world was concerned. But in April 2013, the discovery of such a mistake—actually, a coding error in a spreadsheet, coupled with several other flaws in the analysis—not only became the talk of the economics profession, but made headlines. Looking back, we might even conclude that it changed the course of policy.

Why? Because the paper in question, “Growth in a Time of Debt,” by the Harvard economists Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff, had acquired touchstone status in the debate over economic policy. Ever since the paper was first circulated, austerians—advocates of fiscal austerity, of immediate sharp cuts in government spending—had cited its alleged findings to defend their position and attack their critics. Again and again, suggestions that, as John Maynard Keynes once argued, “the boom, not the slump, is the right time for austerity”—that cuts should wait until economies were stronger—were met with declarations that Reinhart and Rogoff had shown that waiting would be disastrous, that economies fall off a cliff once government debt exceeds 90 percent of GDP.

Indeed, Reinhart-Rogoff may have had more immediate influence on public debate than any previous paper in the history of economics. The 90 percent claim was cited as the decisive argument for austerity by figures ranging from Paul Ryan, the former vice-presidential candidate who chairs the House budget committee, to Olli Rehn, the top economic official at the European Commission, to the editorial board of The Washington Post. So the revelation that the supposed 90 percent threshold was an artifact of programming mistakes, data omissions, and peculiar statistical techniques suddenly made a remarkable number of prominent people look foolish.

The real mystery, however, was why Reinhart-Rogoff was ever taken seriously, let alone canonized, in the first place. Right from the beginning, critics raised strong concerns about the paper’s methodology and conclusions, concerns that should have been enough to give everyone pause. Moreover, Reinhart-Rogoff was actually the second example of a paper seized on as decisive evidence in favor of austerity economics, only to fall apart on careful scrutiny. Much the same thing happened, albeit less spectacularly, after austerians became infatuated with a paper by Alberto Alesina and Silvia Ardagna purporting to show that slashing government spending would have little adverse impact on economic growth and might even be expansionary. Surely that experience should have inspired some caution.

So why wasn’t there more caution? The answer, as documented by some of the books reviewed here and unintentionally illustrated by others, lies in both politics and psychology: the case for austerity was and is one that many powerful people want to believe, leading them to seize on anything that looks like a justification. I’ll talk about that will to believe later in this article. First, however, it’s useful to trace the recent history of austerity both as a doctrine and as a policy experiment.

1.

In the beginning was the bubble. There have been many, many books about the excesses of the boom years—in fact, too many books. For as we’ll see, the urge to dwell on the lurid details of the boom, rather than trying to understand the dynamics of the slump, is a recurrent problem for economics and economic policy. For now, suffice it to say that by the beginning of 2008 both America and Europe were poised for a fall. They had become excessively dependent on an overheated housing market, their households were too deep in debt, their financial sectors were undercapitalized and overextended.

All that was needed to collapse these houses of cards was some kind of adverse shock, and in the end the implosion of US subprime-based securities did the deed. By the fall of 2008 the housing bubbles on both sides of the Atlantic had burst, and the whole North Atlantic economy was caught up in “deleveraging,” a process in which many debtors try—or are forced—to pay down their debts at the same time.

Why is this a problem? Because of interdependence: your spending is my income, and my spending is your income. If both of us try to reduce our debt by slashing spending, both of our incomes plunge—and plunging incomes can actually make our indebtedness worse even as they also produce mass unemployment.

Students of economic history watched the process unfolding in 2008 and 2009 with a cold shiver of recognition, because it was very obviously the same kind of process that brought on the Great Depression. Indeed, early in 2009 the economic historians Barry Eichengreen and Kevin O’Rourke produced shocking charts showing that the first year of the 2008–2009 slump in trade and industrial production was fully comparable to the first year of the great global slump from 1929 to 1933.

So was a second Great Depression about to unfold? The good news was that we had, or thought we had, several big advantages over our grandfathers, helping to limit the damage. Some of these advantages were, you might say, structural, built into the way modern economies operate, and requiring no special action on the part of policymakers. Others were intellectual: surely we had learned something since the 1930s, and would not repeat our grandfathers’ policy mistakes.

On the structural side, probably the biggest advantage over the 1930s was the way taxes and social insurance programs—both much bigger than they were in 1929—acted as “automatic stabilizers.” Wages might fall, but overall income didn’t fall in proportion, both because tax collections plunged and because government checks continued to flow for Social Security, Medicare, unemployment benefits, and more. In effect, the existence of the modern welfare state put a floor on total spending, and therefore prevented the economy’s downward spiral from going too far.

On the intellectual side, modern policymakers knew the history of the Great Depression as a cautionary tale; some, including Ben Bernanke, had actually been major Depression scholars in their previous lives. They had learned from Milton Friedman the folly of letting bank runs collapse the financial system and the desirability of flooding the economy with money in times of panic. They had learned from John Maynard Keynes that under depression conditions government spending can be an effective way to create jobs. They had learned from FDR’s disastrous turn toward austerity in 1937 that abandoning monetary and fiscal stimulus too soon can be a very big mistake.

As a result, where the onset of the Great Depression was accompanied by policies that intensified the slump—interest rate hikes in an attempt to hold on to gold reserves, spending cuts in an attempt to balance budgets—2008 and 2009 were characterized by expansionary monetary and fiscal policies, especially in the United States, where the Federal Reserve not only slashed interest rates, but stepped into the markets to buy everything from commercial paper to long-term government debt, while the Obama administration pushed through an $800 billion program of tax cuts and spending increases. European actions were less dramatic—but on the other hand, Europe’s stronger welfare states arguably reduced the need for deliberate stimulus.

Now, some economists (myself included) warned from the beginning that these monetary and fiscal actions, although welcome, were too small given the severity of the economic shock. Indeed, by the end of 2009 it was clear that although the situation had stabilized, the economic crisis was deeper than policymakers had acknowledged, and likely to prove more persistent than they had imagined. So one might have expected a second round of stimulus to deal with the economic shortfall.

What actually happened, however, was a sudden reversal.

2.

Neil Irwin’s The Alchemists gives us a time and a place at which the major advanced countries abruptly pivoted from stimulus to austerity. The time was early February 2010; the place, somewhat bizarrely, was the remote Canadian Arctic settlement of Iqaluit, where the Group of Seven finance ministers held one of their regularly scheduled summits. Sometimes (often) such summits are little more than ceremonial occasions, and there was plenty of ceremony at this one too, including raw seal meat served at the last dinner (the foreign visitors all declined). But this time something substantive happened. “In the isolation of the Canadian wilderness,” Irwin writes, “the leaders of the world economy collectively agreed that their great challenge had shifted. The economy seemed to be healing; it was time for them to turn their attention away from boosting growth. No more stimulus.”


How decisive was the turn in policy? Figure 1, which is taken from the IMF’s most recent World Economic Outlook, shows how real government spending behaved in this crisis compared with previous recessions; in the figure, year zero is the year before global recession (2008 in the current slump), and spending is compared with its level in that base year. What you see is that the widespread belief that we are experiencing runaway government spending is false—on the contrary, after a brief surge in 2009, government spending began falling in both Europe and the United States, and is now well below its normal trend. The turn to austerity was very real, and quite large.

On the face of it, this was a very strange turn for policy to take. Standard textbook economics says that slashing government spending reduces overall demand, which leads in turn to reduced output and employment. This may be a desirable thing if the economy is overheating and inflation is rising; alternatively, the adverse effects of reduced government spending can be offset. Central banks (the Fed, the European Central Bank, or their counterparts elsewhere) can cut interest rates, inducing more private spending. However, neither of these conditions applied in early 2010, or for that matter apply now. The major advanced economies were and are deeply depressed, with no hint of inflationary pressure. Meanwhile, short-term interest rates, which are more or less under the central bank’s control, are near zero, leaving little room for monetary policy to offset reduced government spending. So Economics 101 would seem to say that all the austerity we’ve seen is very premature, that it should wait until the economy is stronger.

The question, then, is why economic leaders were so ready to throw the textbook out the window.

One answer is that many of them never believed in that textbook stuff in the first place. The German political and intellectual establishment has never had much use for Keynesian economics; neither has much of the Republican Party in the United States. In the heat of an acute economic crisis—as in the autumn of 2008 and the winter of 2009—these dissenting voices could to some extent be shouted down; but once things had calmed they began pushing back hard.

A larger answer is the one we’ll get to later: the underlying political and psychological reasons why many influential figures hate the notions of deficit spending and easy money. Again, once the crisis became less acute, there was more room to indulge in these sentiments.

In addition to these underlying factors, however, were two more contingent aspects of the situation in early 2010: the new crisis in Greece, and the appearance of seemingly rigorous, high-quality economic research that supported the austerian position.

The Greek crisis came as a shock to almost everyone, not least the new Greek government that took office in October 2009. The incoming leadership knew it faced a budget deficit—but it was only after arriving that it learned that the previous government had been cooking the books, and that both the deficit and the accumulated stock of debt were far higher than anyone imagined. As the news sank in with investors, first Greece, then much of Europe, found itself in a new kind of crisis—one not of failing banks but of failing governments, unable to borrow on world markets.

It’s an ill wind that blows nobody good, and the Greek crisis was a godsend for anti-Keynesians. They had been warning about the dangers of deficit spending; the Greek debacle seemed to show just how dangerous fiscal profligacy can be. To this day, anyone arguing against fiscal austerity, let alone suggesting that we need another round of stimulus, can expect to be attacked as someone who will turn America (or Britain, as the case may be) into another Greece.

If Greece provided the obvious real-world cautionary tale, Reinhart and Rogoff seemed to provide the math. Their paper seemed to show not just that debt hurts growth, but that there is a “threshold,” a sort of trigger point, when debt crosses 90 percent of GDP. Go beyond that point, their numbers suggested, and economic growth stalls. Greece, of course, already had debt greater than the magic number. More to the point, major advanced countries, the United States included, were running large budget deficits and closing in on the threshold. Put Greece and Reinhart-Rogoff together, and there seemed to be a compelling case for a sharp, immediate turn toward austerity.

But wouldn’t such a turn toward austerity in an economy still depressed by private deleveraging have an immediate negative impact? Not to worry, said another remarkably influential academic paper, “Large Changes in Fiscal Policy: Taxes Versus Spending,” by Alberto Alesina and Silvia Ardagna.

One of the especially good things in Mark Blyth’s Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea is the way he traces the rise and fall of the idea of “expansionary austerity,” the proposition that cutting spending would actually lead to higher output. As he shows, this is very much a proposition associated with a group of Italian economists (whom he dubs “the Bocconi boys”) who made their case with a series of papers that grew more strident and less qualified over time, culminating in the 2009 analysis by Alesina and Ardagna.

In essence, Alesina and Ardagna made a full frontal assault on the Keynesian proposition that cutting spending in a weak economy produces further weakness. Like Reinhart and Rogoff, they marshaled historical evidence to make their case. According to Alesina and Ardagna, large spending cuts in advanced countries were, on average, followed by expansion rather than contraction. The reason, they suggested, was that decisive fiscal austerity created confidence in the private sector, and this increased confidence more than offset any direct drag from smaller government outlays.

As Mark Blyth documents, this idea spread like wildfire. Alesina and Ardagna made a special presentation in April 2010 to the Economic and Financial Affairs Council of the European Council of Ministers; the analysis quickly made its way into official pronouncements from the European Commission and the European Central Bank. Thus in June 2010 Jean-Claude Trichet, the then president of the ECB, dismissed concerns that austerity might hurt growth:

As regards the economy, the idea that austerity measures could trigger stagnation is incorrect…. In fact, in these circumstances, everything that helps to increase the confidence of households, firms and investors in the sustainability of public finances is good for the consolidation of growth and job creation. I firmly believe that in the current circumstances confidence-inspiring policies will foster and not hamper economic recovery, because confidence is the key factor today.
This was straight Alesina-Ardagna.

By the summer of 2010, then, a full-fledged austerity orthodoxy had taken shape, becoming dominant in European policy circles and influential on this side of the Atlantic. So how have things gone in the almost three years that have passed since?

3.

Clear evidence on the effects of economic policy is usually hard to come by. Governments generally change policies reluctantly, and it’s hard to distinguish the effects of the half-measures they undertake from all the other things going on in the world. The Obama stimulus, for example, was both temporary and fairly small compared with the size of the US economy, never amounting to much more than 2 percent of GDP, and it took effect in an economy whipsawed by the biggest financial crisis in three generations. How much of what took place in 2009–2011, good or bad, can be attributed to the stimulus? Nobody really knows.

The turn to austerity after 2010, however, was so drastic, particularly in European debtor nations, that the usual cautions lose most of their force. Greece imposed spending cuts and tax increases amounting to 15 percent of GDP; Ireland and Portugal rang in with around 6 percent; and unlike the half-hearted efforts at stimulus, these cuts were sustained and indeed intensified year after year. So how did austerity actually work?


The answer is that the results were disastrous—just about as one would have predicted from textbook macroeconomics. Figure 2, for example, shows what happened to a selection of European nations (each represented by a diamond-shaped symbol). The horizontal axis shows austerity measures—spending cuts and tax increases—as a share of GDP, as estimated by the International Monetary Fund. The vertical axis shows the actual percentage change in real GDP. As you can see, the countries forced into severe austerity experienced very severe downturns, and the downturns were more or less proportional to the degree of austerity.

There have been some attempts to explain away these results, notably at the European Commission. But the IMF, looking hard at the data, has not only concluded that austerity has had major adverse economic effects, it has issued what amounts to a mea culpa for having underestimated these adverse effects.*

But is there any alternative to austerity? What about the risks of excessive debt?

In early 2010, with the Greek disaster fresh in everyone’s mind, the risks of excessive debt seemed obvious; those risks seemed even greater by 2011, as Ireland, Spain, Portugal, and Italy joined the ranks of nations having to pay large interest rate premiums. But a funny thing happened to other countries with high debt levels, including Japan, the United States, and Britain: despite large deficits and rapidly rising debt, their borrowing costs remained very low. The crucial difference, as the Belgian economist Paul DeGrauwe pointed out, seemed to be whether countries had their own currencies, and borrowed in those currencies. Such countries can’t run out of money because they can print it if needed, and absent the risk of a cash squeeze, advanced nations are evidently able to carry quite high levels of debt without crisis.

Three years after the turn to austerity, then, both the hopes and the fears of the austerians appear to have been misplaced. Austerity did not lead to a surge in confidence; deficits did not lead to crisis. But wasn’t the austerity movement grounded in serious economic research? Actually, it turned out that it wasn’t—the research the austerians cited was deeply flawed.

First to go down was the notion of expansionary austerity. Even before the results of Europe’s austerity experiment were in, the Alesina-Ardagna paper was falling apart under scrutiny. Researchers at the Roosevelt Institute pointed out that none of the alleged examples of austerity leading to expansion of the economy actually took place in the midst of an economic slump; researchers at the IMF found that the Alesina-Ardagna measure of fiscal policy bore little relationship to actual policy changes. “By the middle of 2011,” Blyth writes, “empirical and theoretical support for expansionary austerity was slipping away.” Slowly, with little fanfare, the whole notion that austerity might actually boost economies slunk off the public stage.

Reinhart-Rogoff lasted longer, even though serious questions about their work were raised early on. As early as July 2010 Josh Bivens and John Irons of the Economic Policy Institute had identified both a clear mistake—a misinterpretation of US data immediately after World War II—and a severe conceptual problem. Reinhart and Rogoff, as they pointed out, offered no evidence that the correlation ran from high debt to low growth rather than the other way around, and other evidence suggested that the latter was more likely. But such criticisms had little impact; for austerians, one might say, Reinhart-Rogoff was a story too good to check.

So the revelations in April 2013 of the errors of Reinhart and Rogoff came as a shock. Despite their paper’s influence, Reinhart and Rogoff had not made their data widely available—and researchers working with seemingly comparable data hadn’t been able to reproduce their results. Finally, they made their spreadsheet available to Thomas Herndon, a graduate student at the University of Massachusetts, Amherst—and he found it very odd indeed. There was one actual coding error, although that made only a small contribution to their conclusions. More important, their data set failed to include the experience of several Allied nations—Canada, New Zealand, and Australia—that emerged from World War II with high debt but nonetheless posted solid growth. And they had used an odd weighting scheme in which each “episode” of high debt counted the same, whether it occurred during one year of bad growth or seventeen years of good growth.

Without these errors and oddities, there was still a negative correlation between debt and growth—but this could be, and probably was, mostly a matter of low growth leading to high debt, not the other way around. And the “threshold” at 90 percent vanished, undermining the scare stories being used to sell austerity.

Not surprisingly, Reinhart and Rogoff have tried to defend their work; but their responses have been weak at best, evasive at worst. Notably, they continue to write in a way that suggests, without stating outright, that debt at 90 percent of GDP is some kind of threshold at which bad things happen. In reality, even if one ignores the issue of causality—whether low growth causes high debt or the other way around—the apparent effects on growth of debt rising from, say, 85 to 95 percent of GDP are fairly small, and don’t justify the debt panic that has been such a powerful influence on policy.

At this point, then, austerity economics is in a very bad way. Its predictions have proved utterly wrong; its founding academic documents haven’t just lost their canonized status, they’ve become the objects of much ridicule. But as I’ve pointed out, none of this (except that Excel error) should have come as a surprise: basic macroeconomics should have told everyone to expect what did, in fact, happen, and the papers that have now fallen into disrepute were obviously flawed from the start.

This raises the obvious question: Why did austerity economics get such a powerful grip on elite opinion in the first place?

4.

Everyone loves a morality play. “For the wages of sin is death” is a much more satisfying message than “Shit happens.” We all want events to have meaning.

When applied to macroeconomics, this urge to find moral meaning creates in all of us a predisposition toward believing stories that attribute the pain of a slump to the excesses of the boom that precedes it—and, perhaps, also makes it natural to see the pain as necessary, part of an inevitable cleansing process. When Andrew Mellon told Herbert Hoover to let the Depression run its course, so as to “purge the rottenness” from the system, he was offering advice that, however bad it was as economics, resonated psychologically with many people (and still does).

By contrast, Keynesian economics rests fundamentally on the proposition that macroeconomics isn’t a morality play—that depressions are essentially a technical malfunction. As the Great Depression deepened, Keynes famously declared that “we have magneto trouble”—i.e., the economy’s troubles were like those of a car with a small but critical problem in its electrical system, and the job of the economist is to figure out how to repair that technical problem. Keynes’s masterwork, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, is noteworthy—and revolutionary—for saying almost nothing about what happens in economic booms. Pre-Keynesian business cycle theorists loved to dwell on the lurid excesses that take place in good times, while having relatively little to say about exactly why these give rise to bad times or what you should do when they do. Keynes reversed this priority; almost all his focus was on how economies stay depressed, and what can be done to make them less depressed.

I’d argue that Keynes was overwhelmingly right in his approach, but there’s no question that it’s an approach many people find deeply unsatisfying as an emotional matter. And so we shouldn’t find it surprising that many popular interpretations of our current troubles return, whether the authors know it or not, to the instinctive, pre-Keynesian style of dwelling on the excesses of the boom rather than on the failures of the slump.

David Stockman’s The Great Deformation should be seen in this light. It’s an immensely long rant against excesses of various kinds, all of which, in Stockman’s vision, have culminated in our present crisis. History, to Stockman’s eyes, is a series of “sprees”: a “spree of unsustainable borrowing,” a “spree of interest rate repression,” a “spree of destructive financial engineering,” and, again and again, a “money-printing spree.” For in Stockman’s world, all economic evil stems from the original sin of leaving the gold standard. Any prosperity we may have thought we had since 1971, when Nixon abandoned the last link to gold, or maybe even since 1933, when FDR took us off gold for the first time, was an illusion doomed to end in tears. And of course, any policies aimed at alleviating the current slump will just make things worse.

In itself, Stockman’s book isn’t important. Aside from a few swipes at Republicans, it consists basically of standard goldbug bombast. But the attention the book has garnered, the ways it has struck a chord with many people, including even some liberals, suggest just how strong remains the urge to see economics as a morality play, three generations after Keynes tried to show us that it is nothing of the kind.

And powerful officials are by no means immune to that urge. In The Alchemists, Neil Irwin analyzes the motives of Jean-Claude Trichet, the president of the European Central Bank, in advocating harsh austerity policies:

Trichet embraced a view, especially common in Germany, that was rooted in a sort of moralism. Greece had spent too much and taken on too much debt. It must cut spending and reduce deficits. If it showed adequate courage and political resolve, markets would reward it with lower borrowing costs. He put a great deal of faith in the power of confidence….
Given this sort of predisposition, is it any wonder that Keynesian economics got thrown out the window, while Alesina-Ardagna and Reinhart-Rogoff were instantly canonized?

So is the austerian impulse all a matter of psychology? No, there’s also a fair bit of self-interest involved. As many observers have noted, the turn away from fiscal and monetary stimulus can be interpreted, if you like, as giving creditors priority over workers. Inflation and low interest rates are bad for creditors even if they promote job creation; slashing government deficits in the face of mass unemployment may deepen a depression, but it increases the certainty of bondholders that they’ll be repaid in full. I don’t think someone like Trichet was consciously, cynically serving class interests at the expense of overall welfare; but it certainly didn’t hurt that his sense of economic morality dovetailed so perfectly with the priorities of creditors.

It’s also worth noting that while economic policy since the financial crisis looks like a dismal failure by most measures, it hasn’t been so bad for the wealthy. Profits have recovered strongly even as unprecedented long-term unemployment persists; stock indices on both sides of the Atlantic have rebounded to pre-crisis highs even as median income languishes. It might be too much to say that those in the top 1 percent actually benefit from a continuing depression, but they certainly aren’t feeling much pain, and that probably has something to do with policymakers’ willingness to stay the austerity course.

5.

How could this happen? That’s the question many people were asking four years ago; it’s still the question many are asking today. But the “this” has changed.

Four years ago, the mystery was how such a terrible financial crisis could have taken place, with so little forewarning. The harsh lessons we had to learn involved the fragility of modern finance, the folly of trusting banks to regulate themselves, and the dangers of assuming that fancy financial arrangements have eliminated or even reduced the age-old problems of risk.

I would argue, however—self-serving as it may sound (I warned about the housing bubble, but had no inkling of how widespread a collapse would follow when it burst)—that the failure to anticipate the crisis was a relatively minor sin. Economies are complicated, ever-changing entities; it was understandable that few economists realized the extent to which short-term lending and securitization of assets such as subprime mortgages had recreated the old risks that deposit insurance and bank regulation were created to control.

I’d argue that what happened next—the way policymakers turned their back on practically everything economists had learned about how to deal with depressions, the way elite opinion seized on anything that could be used to justify austerity—was a much greater sin. The financial crisis of 2008 was a surprise, and happened very fast; but we’ve been stuck in a regime of slow growth and desperately high unemployment for years now. And during all that time policymakers have been ignoring the lessons of theory and history.

It’s a terrible story, mainly because of the immense suffering that has resulted from these policy errors. It’s also deeply worrying for those who like to believe that knowledge can make a positive difference in the world. To the extent that policymakers and elite opinion in general have made use of economic analysis at all, they have, as the saying goes, done so the way a drunkard uses a lamppost: for support, not illumination. Papers and economists who told the elite what it wanted to hear were celebrated, despite plenty of evidence that they were wrong; critics were ignored, no matter how often they got it right.

The Reinhart-Rogoff debacle has raised some hopes among the critics that logic and evidence are finally beginning to matter. But the truth is that it’s too soon to tell whether the grip of austerity economics on policy will relax significantly in the face of these revelations. For now, the broader message of the past few years remains just how little good comes from understanding.

How the Case for Austerity Has Crumbled
Paul Krugman JUNE 6, 2013

The Alchemists: Three Central Bankers and a World on Fire
by Neil Irwin
Penguin, 430 pp., $29.95

Austerity: The History of a Dangerous Idea
by Mark Blyth
Oxford University Press, 288 pp., $24.95

The Great Deformation: The Corruption of Capitalism in America
by David A. Stockman
PublicAffairs, 742 pp., $35.00



Nessun commento:

Posta un commento

Informazioni

Questo blog non rappresenta una testata giornalistica in quanto viene aggiornato senza alcuna periodicità. Non può pertanto considerarsi un prodotto editoriale ai sensi della legge n. 62 del 7.03.2001. Parte delle immagini, loghi, contributi audio o video e testi usati in questo blog viene dalla Rete e i diritti d'autore appartengono ai rispettivi proprietari. Il blog non è responsabile dei commenti inseriti dagli utenti e lettori occasionali.